Dictionary Definition
monopoly
Noun
1 (economics) a market in which there are many
buyers but only one seller; "a monopoly on silver"; "when you have
a monopoly you can ask any price you like"
2 exclusive control or possession of something;
"They have no monopoly on intelligence"
3 a board game in which players try to gain a
monopoly on real estate as pieces advance around the board
according to the throw of a die
User Contributed Dictionary
see Monopoly
English
Pronunciation
- (RP): mənŏ'pəlē", /məˈnɒpəˌli/, /m@"nQp@%li/
- (US): mənä'pəlē", /məˈnɑpəˌli/, /m@"nAp@%li/
Noun
Translations
- Bulgarian: монопол
- Chinese (simplified): 独占 (duzhan)
- Chinese (traditional): 獨佔
- Danish: monopol
- Dutch: monopolie
- Finnish: monopoli
- French: monopole
- German: Monopol,
- Greek, Ancient μονοπώλιον (monopolion)
- Greek, Modern μονοπώλιο (monopolio)
- Hebrew: מונופול (Monopol)
- Indonesian: monopoli
- Italian: monopoli, monopolio
- Japanese: 独占 (どくせん dokusen), 専売 (せんばい)
- Korean: 전매권
- Latin: monopolium
- Norwegian: monopol
- Portuguese: monopólio
- Romanian: monopol
- Russian: монополия
- Spanish: monopolio
See also
Extensive Definition
The term monopoly (from Greek
monos , alone or single + polein , to sell) can bear two main
definitions:
- In Economics, monopoly (also "Pure oligopoly") exists when a specific individual or enterprise has sufficient control over a particular product or service to determine significantly the terms on which other individuals shall have access to it. Monopolies are thus characterized by a lack of economic competition for the good or service that they provide and a lack of viable substitute goods. Alternatively (a modern and less common usage), it may be used as a verb or adjective to refer to the process (see Monopolism) by which a firm gains persistently greater market share than what is expected under perfect competition. The latter usage of the term is invoked in the theory of monopolistic competition.
- In political discourse, the term monopoly is frequently invoked as a blanket generalization in criticism of firms with large market share or lack of what's perceived as "fair" competition.
The latter usage of the term is more predominant
among non-economists than economists and while its assertions may
hold true, it is not based upon the definition of "monopoly," used
by economists.
A monopoly should be distinguished from monopsony, in which there is
only one buyer of a product or service; a monopoly may also have
monopsony control of a sector of a market. Likewise, a monopoly
should be distinguished from a cartel (a form of oligopoly), in which several
providers act together to coordinate services, prices or sale of
goods.
A government-granted
monopoly or legal monopoly is sanctioned by the state, often to
provide an incentive to invest in a risky venture or enrich a
domestic constituency.
The government may also reserve the venture for itself, thus
forming a government
monopoly.
Economic analysis
- No close substitutes: A monopoly is not merely the state of having control over a product; it also means that there is no real alternative to the monopolised product.
- A price maker: Because a single firm controls the total supply in a pure monopoly, it is able to exert a significant degree of control over the price by changing the quantity supplied.
Other common assumptions in modeling monopolies
include the presence of multiple buyers (if a firm is the only
buyer, it also has a monopsony), an identical price
for all buyers, and asymmetric
information.
A company with a monopoly does not undergo price
pressure from competitors, although it may face pricing pressure
from potential competition. If a company raises prices too high,
then others may enter the market if they are able to provide the
same good, or a substitute, at a lower price. The idea that
monopolies in markets with easy entry need not be regulated against
is known as the "revolution in monopoly theory".
A monopolist can extract only one premium, and
getting into complementary markets does not pay. That is, the total
profits a monopolist could earn if it sought to leverage its
monopoly in one market by monopolizing a complementary market are
equal to the extra profits it could earn anyway by charging more
for the monopoly product itself.
However, the one monopoly profit theorem does not
hold true if there exist:
- Stranded customers in the monopoly good.
- Poorly informed customers.
- High fixed costs in the tied good.
- Economies of scale in the tied good.
- Price regulations for the monopoly product
Price setting for unregulated monopolies
In economics, a firm facing the entire market
demand
curve is said to have monopoly power. This is in contrast to a
price-taking
firm, which operates in a negligible segment of the overall market
and thus faces a demand curve with infinite price elasticity.
The pricing and production choices made by these firms follow
identical decision rules. That is, regardless of the type of firm,
the profit maximizing price and quantity choice will equate the
marginal
cost and marginal
revenue of production (see diagram). The key difference is in
the outcome of such a rule: typically a monopoly selects a higher
price and lower quantity than a price-taking firm.
There are important points for one to remember
when considering the monopoly model diagram (and its associated
conclusions) displayed here. The result that monopoly prices are
higher, and production output lower, than a competitive firm follow
from a requirement that the monopoly not charge different prices
for different customers. That is, the monopoly is restricted from
engaging in price
discrimination. If the monopoly were permitted to charge
individualized prices, the quantity produced, and the price charged
to the marginal customer, would be identical to a competitive firm,
thus eliminating the deadweight
loss.
As long as the
price elasticity of demand for most customers is less than one
in absolute
value, it is advantageous for a firm to increase its prices: it
then receives more money for fewer goods. With a price increase,
price elasticity tends to rise, and in the optimum case above it
will be greater than one for most customers. The following formula
gives the relation among price, marginal cost of production and
demand elasticity that maximizes a monopoly profit: P(1-\frac1e) =
MC where (e) is the elasticity of demand. A monopoly's power is
given by the vertical distance between the point at which the
marginal cost curve (MC) intersects with the marginal revenue curve
(MR) and the demand curve. The longer the vertical distance, (i.e.,
the more inelastic the demand curve) the greater the monopoly's
power, and thus, the larger its profits.
Calculating monopoly output
The single price monopoly profit maximization problem is as follows:The monopoly profit is its total revenue less its
total cost. Let the price it sets as a market response be a
function of the quantity it produces (Q) P(Q) and let its cost
function be as a function of quantity C(Q). The monopoly's revenue
is the product of the price and the quantity it produces. Hence its
profit is:
- \Pi\ = P(Q)\cdot Q - C(Q)
Taking the first order derivative with respect to
quantity yields:
- \frac = P'(Q)\cdot Q + P(Q) - C'(Q)
Setting this equal to zero for
maximization:
- \frac = P'(Q)\cdot Q + P(Q) - C'(Q)=0
- \frac + C'(Q) = P'(Q)\cdot Q + P(Q)= C'(Q)
- \frac = P(Q)\cdot Q + 2\cdot P'(Q) - C(Q)
(the rate of marginal revenue is less than the
rate of marginal cost, for maximization).
This procedure assumes that the monopolist knows
the exact demand function.
Monopoly and efficiency
According to standard economic theory (see analysis above), a monopoly will sell a lower quantity of goods at a higher price than firms would in a purely competitive market. The monopoly will secure monopoly profits by appropriating some or all of the consumer surplus. Since the loss in consumer surplus is higher than the monopolist's gain, this creates deadweight loss, which is inefficient and a form of market failure.Negative aspects
It is often argued that monopolies tend to become less efficient and innovative over time, becoming "complacent giants", because they do not have to be efficient or innovative to compete in the marketplace. Sometimes this very loss of efficiency can raise a potential competitor's value enough to overcome market entry barriers, or provide incentive for research and investment into new alternatives. The theory of contestable markets argues that in some circumstances (private) monopolies are forced to behave as if there were competition because of the risk of losing their monopoly to new entrants. This is likely to happen where a market's barriers to entry are low. It might also be because of the availability in the longer term of substitutes in other markets. For example, a canal monopoly, while worth a great deal in the late eighteenth century United Kingdom,was worth much less in the late nineteenth century because of the introduction of railways as a substitute.Positive aspects
Some argue that it can be good to allow a firm to attempt to monopolize a market, since practices such as dumping can benefit consumers in the short term; and once the firm grows too big, it can be dealt with via regulation. When monopolies are not broken through the open market, often a government will step in, either to regulate the monopoly, turn it into a publicly owned monopoly, or forcibly break it up (see Antitrust law). Public utilities, often being natural monopolies and less susceptible to efficient breakup, are often strongly regulated or publicly owned. AT&T and Standard Oil are debatable examples of the breakup of a private monopoly. When AT&T was broken up into the "Baby Bell" components, MCI, Sprint, and other companies were able to compete effectively in the long distance phone market and began to take phone traffic from the less efficient AT&T.Hotelling's law
Mathematician Harold Hotelling came up with Hotelling's law which showed that there exist cases where monopoly has advantages for the consumer. If there is a beach where customers are distributed evenly along it, an entrepreneur setting up an ice cream stand would naturally place it in the middle of the beach. A competing ice cream seller would do best to place his competing ice cream stand next to it to gain half the market share, but two stalls right next to each other is not an ideal situation for the people on the beach. A monopolist who owns both stalls on the other hand, would distribute his ice cream stalls some distance apart.The "natural monopoly" problem
A natural monopoly is defined as a theoretical situation in which production is characterized by falling long-run marginal cost throughout the relevant output range. In such situations, a policy of laissez-faire must result in a single seller. The conventional Paretian solution to market failure of this kind is public regulation (in the United States) or public enterprise (in the United Kingdom).Historical monopolies
Common salt (sodium
chloride) historically gave rise to natural monopolies. Until
recently, a combination of strong sunshine and low humidity or an
extension of peat marshes was necessary for winning salt from the
sea, the most plentiful source. Changing sea levels periodically
caused salt "famines" and
communities were forced to depend upon those who controlled the
scarce inland mines and salt springs, which were often in hostile
areas (the Dead Sea, the
Sahara
desert) requiring well-organized security for transport,
storage, and distribution. The "Gabelle", a
notoriously high tax levied upon salt, played a role in the start
of the French
Revolution, when strict legal controls were in place over who
was allowed to sell and distribute salt.
Examples of alleged and legal monopolies
- The salt commission, a legal monopoly in China formed in 758.
- British East India Company; created as a legal trading monopoly in 1600.
- Dutch East India Company; created as a legal trading monopoly in 1602.
- U.S. Steel; anti-trust prosecution failed in 1911.
- Standard Oil; broken up in 1911.
- National Football League; survived anti-trust lawsuit in the 1960s, convicted of being an illegal monopoly in the 1980s.
- Major League Baseball; survived U.S. anti-trust litigation in 1922, though its special status is still in dispute as of 2008.
- United Aircraft and Transport Corporation; aircraft manufacturer holding company forced to divest itself of airlines in 1934.
- American Telephone & Telegraph; telecommunications giant broken up in 1982.
- Microsoft; settled anti-trust litigation in the U.S. in 2001; fined by the European Commission in 2004, which was upheld for the most part by the Court of First Instance of the European Communities in 2007. The fine was 1.35 Billion USD in 2008 for incompliance with the 2004 rule.
- De Beers; settled charges of price fixing in the diamond trade in the 2000s.
- Joint Commission; has a monopoly over whether or not US hospitals are able to participate in the Medicare and Medicaid programs.
- Telecom New Zealand; local loop unbundling enforced by central government.
- Monsanto has been sued by competitors for anti-trust and monopolistic practices. They hold between 70% and 100% of the commercial seed market.
See also
Proposed benefits
Monopolistic practices
Simulation of Monopoly Market
General
Notes and references
Further reading
- Guy Ankerl, Beyond Monopoly Capitalism and Monopoly Socialism. Cambridge,Mass.: Schenkman Pbl., 1978. ISBN0870739387
- Impact of Antitrust Laws on American Professional Team Sports
External links
- Monopoly: A Brief Introduction by The Linux Information Project
- Monopoly by Elmer G. Wiens: Online Interactive Models of Monopoly (Public or Private) and Oligopoly
- Monopoly Profit and Loss by Fiona Maclachlan and and Natural Monopoly by Seth J. Chandler, The Wolfram Demonstrations Project.
Criticism
- Natural Monopoly and Its Regulation
- The Myth of the Natural Monopoly
- Natural Monopoly and Its Regulation
- From rulers' monopolies to users' choices A critical survey of monopolistic practices
monopoly in Arabic: احتكار
monopoly in Bengali: একচেটিয়া কারবার
monopoly in Bosnian: Monopol
monopoly in Bulgarian: Монопол
monopoly in Catalan: Monopoli
monopoly in Czech: Monopol
monopoly in Danish: Monopol
monopoly in German: Monopol
monopoly in Estonian: Monopol
monopoly in Modern Greek (1453-):
Μονοπώλιο
monopoly in Spanish: Monopolio
monopoly in Esperanto: Monopolo
monopoly in Basque: Monopolio
monopoly in French: Monopole
monopoly in Galician: Monopolio
monopoly in Korean: 독점
monopoly in Croatian: Monopol
monopoly in Indonesian: Pasar monopoli
monopoly in Italian: Monopolio
monopoly in Hebrew: מונופול
monopoly in Latvian: Monopols
monopoly in Lithuanian: Monopolija
monopoly in Hungarian: Monopólium
monopoly in Macedonian: Монопол
monopoly in Dutch: Monopolie
monopoly in Japanese: 独占
monopoly in Norwegian: Monopol
monopoly in Norwegian Nynorsk: Monopol
monopoly in Polish: Monopol
monopoly in Portuguese: Monopólio
monopoly in Romanian: Monopol
monopoly in Russian: Монополия
monopoly in Simple English: Monopoly
monopoly in Slovak: Monopol ponuky
monopoly in Serbian: Монопол
monopoly in Serbo-Croatian: Monopol
monopoly in Finnish: Monopoli
monopoly in Swedish: Monopol
monopoly in Vietnamese: Độc quyền (kinh
tế)
monopoly in Turkish: Tekel
monopoly in Ukrainian: Монополія
monopoly in Chinese: 垄断
Synonyms, Antonyms and Related Words
a corner on, arrest, arrestation, bear raid, bull
raid, cartel, check, consortium, constraint, control, cooling, cooling down, cooling
off, copyright,
corner, corner in,
cornering, curb, curtailment, deceleration, engrossment, exclusive
possession, forestallment, hindrance, inhibition, injunction, interdict, legal restraint,
manipulation,
monopolization,
ownership, pool, possessorship, prohibition, proprietorship, protection, protectionism, protective
tariff, raid, rationing, rein, restraint, restraint of trade,
retardation,
retrenchment,
rigging, self-control,
slowing down, syndicate, tariff wall,
thought control, trust,
wash sale, washing